The
recent correction in the US stock market is now being characterized as a
fleeting aberration – a volatility shock – in what is still deemed to
be a very accommodating investment climate. In fact, for a US economy
that has a razor-thin cushion of saving, dependence on rising asset
prices has never been more obvious.
The
spin is all too predictable. With the US stock market clawing its way
back from the sharp correction of early February, the mindless mantra of
the great bull market has returned. The recent correction is now being
characterized as a fleeting aberration – a volatility shock – in what is
still deemed to be a very accommodating investment climate. After all,
the argument goes, economic fundamentals – not just in the United
States, but worldwide – haven’t been this good in a long, long time.
The Year Ahead 2018
The world’s leading thinkers and policymakers examine what’s come apart in the past year, and anticipate what will define the year ahead.
But
are the fundamentals really that sound? For a US economy that has a
razor-thin cushion of saving, nothing could be further from the truth.
America’s net national saving rate – the sum of saving by businesses,
households, and the government sector – stood at just 2.1% of national
income in the third quarter of 2017. That is only one-third the 6.3%
average that prevailed in the final three decades of the twentieth
century.
It
is important to think about saving in “net” terms, which excludes the
depreciation of obsolete or worn-out capacity in order to assess how
much the economy is putting aside to fund the expansion of productive
capacity. Net saving represents today’s investment in the future, and
the bottom line for America is that it is saving next to nothing.
Alas,
the story doesn’t end there. To finance consumption and growth, the US
borrows surplus saving from abroad to compensate for the domestic
shortfall. All that borrowing implies a large balance-of-payments
deficit with the rest of the world, which spawns an equally large trade
deficit. While President Donald Trump’s administration is hardly
responsible for this sad state of affairs, its policies are about to
make a tough situation far worse.
Under
the guise of tax reform, late last year Trump signed legislation that
will increase the federal budget deficit by $1.5 trillion over the next
decade. And now the US Congress, in its infinite wisdom, has upped the
ante by another $300 billion in the latest deal to avert a government
shutdown. Never mind that deficit spending makes no sense when the
economy is nearing full employment: this sharp widening of the federal
deficit is enough, by itself, to push the already-low net national
saving rate toward zero. And it’s not just the government’s red ink that
is so troublesome. The personal saving rate fell to 2.4% of disposable
(after-tax) income in December 2017, the lowest in 12 years and only
about a quarter of the 9.3% average that prevailed over the final three
decades of the twentieth century.
As
domestic saving plunges, the US has two options – a reduction in
investment and the economic growth it supports, or increased borrowing
of surplus saving from abroad. Over the past 35 years, America has
consistently opted for the latter, running balance-of-payments deficits
every year since 1982 (with a minor exception in 1991, reflecting
foreign contributions for US military expenses in the Gulf War). With
these deficits, of course, come equally chronic trade deficits with a
broad cross-section of America’s foreign partners. Astonishingly, in
2017, the US ran trade deficits with 102 countries.
The
multilateral foreign-trade deficits of a saving-short US economy set
the stage for perhaps the most egregious policy blunder being committed
by the Trump administration: a shift toward protectionism. Further
compression of an already-weak domestic saving position spells growing
current-account and trade deficits – a fundamental axiom of
macroeconomics that the US never seems to appreciate.
Attempting
to solve a multilateral imbalance with bilateral tariffs directed
mainly at China, such as those just imposed on solar panels and washing
machines in January, doesn’t add up. And, given the growing likelihood
of additional trade barriers – as suggested by the US Commerce
Department’s recent recommendations of high tariffs on aluminum and
steel – the combination of protectionism and ever-widening trade
imbalances becomes all the more problematic for a US economy set to
become even more dependent on foreign capital. Far from sound, the
fundamentals of a saving-short US economy look shakier than ever.
Lacking
a cushion of solid support from income generation, the lack of saving
also leaves the US far more beholden to fickle asset markets than might
otherwise be the case. That’s especially true of American consumers who
have relied on appreciation of equity holdings and home values to
support over-extended lifestyles. It is also the case for the US Federal
Reserve, which has turned to unconventional monetary policies to
support the real economy via so-called wealth effects. And, of course,
foreign investors are acutely sensitive to relative returns on assets –
the US versus other markets – as well as the translation of those
returns into their home currencies.
Driven
by the momentum of trends in employment, industrial production,
consumer sentiment, and corporate earnings, the case for sound
fundamentals plays like a broken record during periods of financial
market volatility. But momentum and fundamentals are two very different
things. Momentum can be fleeting, especially for a saving-short US
economy that is consuming the seed corn of future prosperity. With
dysfunctional policies pointing to a further compression of saving in
the years ahead, the myth of sound US fundamentals has never rung more
hollow.
More:
Aucun commentaire:
Enregistrer un commentaire
Ce blog est ouvert à la contradiction par la voie de commentaires. Je tiens ce blog depuis fin 2005; je n'ai aucune ambition ni politique ni de notoriété. C'est mon travail de retraité pour la collectivité. Tout lecteur peut commenter sous email google valide. Tout peut être écrit mais dans le respect de la liberté de penser de chacun et la courtoisie.
- Je modère tous les commentaires pour éviter le spam et d'autres entrées malheureuses possibles.
- Cela peut prendre un certain temps avant que votre commentaire n'apparaisse, surtout si je suis en déplacement.
- Je n'autorise pas les attaques personnelles. Je considère cependant que ces attaques sont différentes des attaques contre des idées soutenues par des personnes. Si vous souhaitez attaquer des idées, c'est bien, mais vous devez alors fournir des arguments et vous engager dans la discussion.
- Je n'autorise pas les commentaires susceptibles d'être diffamatoires (au mieux que je puisse juger car je ne suis pas juriste) ou qui utilisent un langage excessif qui n'est pas nécessaire pour l'argumentation présentée.
- Veuillez ne pas publier de liens vers des publicités - le commentaire sera simplement supprimé.
- Je suis pour la liberté d'expression, mais il faut être pertinent. La pertinence est mesurée par la façon dont le commentaire s'apparente au sujet du billet auquel le commentaire s'adresse. Si vous voulez juste parler de quelque chose, créez votre propre blog. Mais puisqu'il s'agit de mon blog, je vous invite à partager mon point de vue ou à rebondir sur les points de vue enregistrés par d'autres commentaires. Pour ou contre c'est bien.
- Je considère aussi que la liberté d'expression porte la responsabilité d'être le propriétaire de cette parole.
J'ai noté que ceux qui tombent dans les attaques personnelles (que je supprime) le font de manière anonyme... Ensuite, ils ont l'audace de suggérer que j'exerce la censure.